Showing posts with label medicare. Show all posts
Showing posts with label medicare. Show all posts

Tuesday, August 17, 2010

e-Health, Telemedicine, and Elections

HP and Dreamworks' Halo Videoconferencing Solution.
Completely unnecessary for doctors, but it sure looks cool.
I love e-things. I am a gadgety sort of person – and yes, I do have a fancy super-duper iPaddy kind of thing. I consider myself to be techno-savvy, and run my private practice with an almost paperless electronic records system. I am an early adopter of many technologies, and will always try new things. But I am not so convinced on e-Health. Why?

e-Health is all the rage. The federal government even has a special taskforce called NEHTA (National e-Health Transition Agency) which is dedicated to wasting investing money in this area. It is all about "transforming and revolutionising" the way we practice medicine.

I don't want to transform and revolutionise anything. I just want to be able to treat my patients better and more easily. This does not require me to have access to every piece of medical documentation on a patient since they were born. It does not require me to be able to access a full medication list and prescribe remotely to a patient on the other side of the country. It also does not require me to videoconference with every patient or doctor in the country.

We have many, many technologies today which make things easier. Often they are the simplest things, and usually they are so pervasive and useful that we take them for granted, like the telephone.

Now, it would be remiss of me not to point out that we are in the latter half of a Federal Election campaign here in Australia. What prompts this post is not the lack of comprehensive health-care policy discussion from either major political party so far, nor the incessant, disproportionate focus on mental health whenever any health funding is mentioned. Julia Gillard's health policy is "Doctors are expensive so let's replace them with technology, physician assistants, nurse practitioners and allied health." Tony Abbott's health policy is "It's too hard let's just hand it to local communities."

But it does bug me that Julia Gillard can stand up and say that she will fund a revolutionary new "Online Consultation" service with a new Medicare Item Number. This is a government whose Health Minister, Nicola Roxon, has been trying very hard to slash item numbers such as those for Cataract Surgery, Obstetric Services, Coronary Angiography, Joint Injection, and Injection Sclerotherapy for Varicose Veins (MBS Website). There is no doubt that this is merely an "election sweetener" for rural GPs and rural voters, and those employed in the technology infrastructure sector.

Steady uptake in Telepsychiatry.
An item number already exists for Telepsychiatry consultations (Items 353-370), and uptake has been gradual - pushed primarily by a small number of psychiatry groups. One might think that psychiatric consults are ideal for videoconference but remember that a great deal of patient interaction is via non-verbal communication and behavioural cues, which even videoconferencing cannot replicate. The RANZCP has guidelines as to how they recommend Telepsychiatry be used.

But much as videoconferencing might be the poster-boy of this type of technology, it ignores the fact that there are many simpler and commoner means by which clinical information is communicated between patients, GPs and specialists, such as email and the telephone.

For example, this policy announcement outlines a scenario whereby a patient might conduct a combined GP visit with an online videoconference to an oncologist. Presumably this is encouraged by the GP and the Oncologist both being able to claim an item number for this consultation.

The key parts of this conference are that first of all, the patient knows that the oncologist exists and is not a figment of the GP's imagination (but there are other means of achieving this) and secondly, the GP is able to discuss the patient's individual treatment plan with a distant oncologist (which is best done in private away from the patient). Given that the private conference is the most important, why restrict any Medicare benefits to a combined patient-GP-specialist consultation?

Currently, patients who will not or cannot travel to see an oncologist can be cared for by a GP or local physician, with instructing care issued by a remote oncologist by much more prosaic technologies as mail, or telephone. Video-conferencing is sometimes used for multidisciplinary team meetings. Realistically, the video adds very little to such meetings or discussions, so it is silly to think that an item number must insist on the conference occurring via video-link. In that setting, should Medicare benefits be available for specialists who spend their time giving advice over the telephone, or reviewing patient files and sending a letter of advice?

If that is the case, then I should be paid Medicare benefits for all the GP queries that I get over the phone, and all the paperwork that I perform organising a patient's care in between physically seeing them. Instead of seeing review patients, I could just check their results, give them a phone call, and lodge the Medicare claim. Is that good or bad? It sure would make my job easier. I could see more patients. It would be significantly cheaper and more convenient for the patient. Even better, if the new Government were to fund practice nurses for specialists, then I could delegate the job to my nurse!

First patient to survive a stroke without side effects?
BULLSHIT! What a way to blow your own trumpet!

Why is it that when you slap a computer with the Internet on it, everything suddenly becomes "Telemedicine"? Since the telephone was introduced doctors have been giving instructions from remote. Is that "Telemedicine?" For years I have been reviewing photos of patients and their X-Rays via email from distant GPs. Am I on the cutting edge of Telemedicine? I have had remote PACS access to a number of hospitals and reviewed films from home. I have advised surgeons and GPs in other towns how to perform surgical procedures over the telephone. Should I be on the news because I am a frontier Tele-surgeon? I don't think so... this is just part of the pervasiveness of communications technology into common life, as well as medicine.

I don't know about you, but this thing
would scare the crap out of me.
My advice, Julia – scrap the "Online Consultations" rubbish and bring in an item number that pays doctors for all the organisational work involved in-between face-to-face patient visits, allow doctors to be paid for telephone consults, advice and services, and don't bother wasting money on teaching doctors to videoconference when they will use it perhaps once of twice a year just for fun. Spend the money on secure integrated email for all doctors and practices. Oh, and funding for specialist practice nurses please.


Tuesday, March 09, 2010

Reform for Reform's Sake?

It has been a big week in healthcare news. One cannot have missed all the talk about Kevin Rudd's bold new plan, to take health care where health care has never been before (except in Victoria). Much of these reforms derive from the previously published NHHRC report which I will not expand upon. I will, however, give some of my mind on efficiency in the medical sector.

Nicola Roxon loves banging on about efficiency, and funding the "efficient costs" of health care. Here she is on ABC's Lateline on the 27th of July last year:

NICOLA ROXON: Yes. Yeah, that's right. They - of the funding, what they recommend - and remember we're talking about their proposals to us - is 40 per cent of efficient funding, which is actually an interesting concept, which is the states should fund the extra 60 per cent and any inefficiencies that are in their system. And they even say if you even went up to 100 per cent in the future, you should only pay 100 per cent of an efficient system, which would sort of have a penalty there for -

TONY JONES: Just to clear up what that means. Effectively, that means that, centrally, you would set the actual cost that should be charged for individual operations. A hip replacement, for example, should cost X and that would be the efficient cost.

NICOLA ROXON: That's right. Yep. That's right.

TONY JONES: Inefficient costs would be anything above X, is that right?

NICOLA ROXON: That's right. And so you would have a activity-based and efficiency-based payment. So if hospitals were - in particular states were not good at particular procedures, they would bear the extra cost, or if you're in a booming state where you've got a higher population putting more demand on your hospital services, you get paid more because you're undertaking more activity. That's the key tool that they are recommending we use for funding, which is a big change from where
we are in block funding the states for their whole activities.

Nicola Roxon - ABC Lateline - July 27 2009

There is plenty in the media about the pros and cons of a central pricing authority, and either additional or streamlined bureaucracy (depending on your point of view), but I am more interested in the "efficiency" concept. Now, efficiency in health care can be measured in very different ways, but generally they do not directly relate to improved health care, quality of life, or prolonged life expectancy. Efficiency does not automatically lead to improved population health.

The usual argument is that if you treat more patients with the same amount of money, then you are benefiting more people and therefore improving the health of your population. That is great if you have lots of waste and slack in your system but that is a very managerial and administrative view of the world. There is, of course, a great deal of waste and slack in our health system nationwide partly because health events are by their nature episodic and unpredictable (just look at the recent swine flu pandemic) and health infrastructure is not something that can be ramped up and down as necessary.

An analogous situation would be that your would not want all fire stations to be working at full capacity all the time, because when a particularly nasty factory blaze occurred there would be nobody to fight it. There is therefore an inherent downside at encouraging hospitals to work at > 90% bed capacity.

Unfortunately the usual measure of efficiency is throughput, which features very highly in health-administration KPIs (also known as "Key Performance Indicators"). For example, a standard means of measuring emergency department efficiency is how many patients are treated in a day, or a month or a year. Similarly we often ask how many patients are seen in a clinic, how many patients are admitted or discharged from hospital, how many operations performed in a month, patients taken off a waiting list, etc.

Obviously these are very simplistic views of the world and so token attempts are made to complicate things by "weighting", or "prioritising", or adding "descriptors" - all managerial jargon-speak for abstracting these figures from real life. The reason these KPIs predominate are:
  1. They are readily reproducible (there is a defined common method for calculating these KPIs)
  2. They are readily manipulated (there is no point monitoring a KPI unless you can improve it... ostensibly by improving performance, but in reality by a short term funding boost, or changing the way it is calculated)
  3. They are readily manipulated in the short term (there is no point monitoring a KPI that takes 20 or 30 years to improve upon)

But back to the point I wanted to make. Kevin Rudd's whole health reform is said to be about eliminating State and Federal buckpassing, or the "blame game" as he likes to put it. This is mere political smoke and mirrors for what is the real purpose of these reforms. I am not saying that this is not worthwhile or important reform - but it should be seen for what it is.

The Blame Game
It has always been human nature to seek to blame someone else for your troubles. Currently our public hospital system is composed of infrastructure funding which comes from Federal and State Governments, recurrent operational funding which comes from State Governments (except when Federal Goverments seek short term headlines by giving away more money), and an Aged-Care system which comes from Federal Government funding.

All of these systems are interdependent, and the only thing that is really being changed is that the Federal Government is proposing to pay for recurrent operational funding through these new reforms. This pays for wages and consumables but who will pay for rebuilding a hospital or adding ICU beds? Who will decide whether a new hospital should be built or relocated against parochial or local interests? It is only natural that every resident wants to have every subspecialty service at their local and nearest hospital, even when this is a recipe for substandard care or unsustainable funding, and rural hospitals need to focus on core services and expanded primary care roles (PDF). Who will make the hard decision to remove maternity, or paediatric, or oncology services from some hospitals and centralise them at another? I'm no expert, but I don't see the Federal Government Reformists putting their hands out - and so the blame game continues.

Furthermore, Victorian Hospitals regularly find ways to manipulate the case-mix funding system to try to squeeze extra money out of the State Government. This is not unethical or immoral - it is just a fact of how the system is designed that a hospital cannot remain viable other than to make the most of the system under which it operates, and if that means improving your funding by meeting the targets in a innovative manner, then that is what the system encourages. Just like Darwinian evolution. Only now, hospitals (and State Governments) will be working hard to find ways to maximise the Federal Government's "Efficient Costs" payments. Get ready for some creative accounting, Kevin!

The Real Reform
The underlying purpose of this reform is no secret - it is merely obscured and obfuscated by the "Blame Game" argument. Kevin Rudd himself has said in his Australia Day Speech:

Treasury analysis which will be contained in the Government's upcoming Australia 2050 report points to the fact that over the next 40 years real health spending on those aged 65 and older is expected to increase around seven-fold. Real health spending on those aged 85 and over is expected to increase 12 fold.

This is a product of the increasing age of Australians overall and secondly the fact that within innovations in pharmaceuticals and medical technologies and the rest the cost of treating each individual aged Australian will rise as well. That is our first problem.

The second problem is, of course, the proportion of Australians in the workforce generating the tax revenue to support those services will become less.

So what does Australia, in response to this 2050 report that we will release soon, do about the challenges for the future when it comes to this ageing of our population.

One further thought we should bear in mind is the impact on our budgets.

Forty years ago, Australian Government spending on health equated to 1.2 per cent of Gross Domestic Product.

In 2010, Australian Government health spending equates to 4 per cent of GDP, and the Intergenerational Report projects that it will rise to 7.1 per cent in 2050.

In dollar terms, that's an increase of over $200 billion by 2050 - and equates to an increase in average Australian Government health spending per person in real terms from $2,290 today to $7,210 in 2050.

These are figures we should all reflect on.

Rising health and hospitals spending is already having an impact on state budgets.

States and territories have experienced growth in health spending of around 11 per cent per year over the past five years.

This contrasts with growth in state revenues of around 3 to 4 per cent a year.

Rapidly rising health costs create a real risk, absent major policy change, as state governments will be overwhelmed by their rising health spending obligations.

If current spending and revenue trends continue, Treasury projects that the total health spending of all states will exceed 100 per cent of their tax revenues, excluding the GST, by around 2045-46 - and possibly earlier in some states.


The NSW treasury has estimated that spending on health will almost double as a share of the NSW total Budget - from 30 per cent today to around 55 per cent in 2032-33.

These are challenging statistics, but it is important the nation becomes familiar with them, because we must do something about them.

Without reform - States ability to provide the services they currently provide will be significantly strained.

That is why 2010 must be and will be a year of major health reform.

Prime Minister Address to Australia Day reception, Sydney - 24 January 2010

The one success of Stephen Duckett's Victorian Case-Mix Funding model is that it has reduced the episodic cost of treating patients in public hospitals. Basically the way it works is that for patients being admitted to hospital with a specific condition (or similar groups of conditions, or similar operations) they receive a set payment which is predetermined. In order to allow for variations in the cost of treating those conditions throughout the state or between hospitals, or the State Government's desire for each hospital to provide various types of services, a complex series of calculations are applied to the actual amount that a hospital can receive. Effectively, hospitals are given a target of patients to treat or procedures to perform. If a hospital goes over that target either on a patient-by-patient basis or over a financial quarter then there is no further funding - they lose money.

In order to determine the appropriate payment, an audit is performed to estimate the costs involved with treating a standard patient in each hospital. This is compared to hospitals statewide and a statistical target is generated. Year upon year these figures are revised with more data, and hospitals try to make a little extra profit by beating their previous year's performance, until you get a "steady state efficient price" which is the price at which a hospital (the cheapest hospital) can treat a patient, most likely by cutting corners and taking risks - i.e. the price at which it starts to become unsafe to treat that patient.

As I intimated earlier - this is all about meeting budgetary targets, not about providing quality care. Doctors and nurses at the coalface are generally divorced from the cost of treating patients. Generally we like it that way as I don't feel guilty doing an ERCP on an 89 year old woman who will die in the next six months of a cholangiocarcinoma even if I save her life today. From a budgetary perspective the hospital would much prefer that I operated on a 20 year old man with early appendicitis than put the ERCP stent in, because it costs less to treat the appendix than the stent, but I have the luxury of not giving a shit, and therefore I am responsible for blowing out the health budget, as Kevin Rudd says.

There are perverse outcomes to this system (or "innovative solutions" depending which side of the fence you sit on). For example, the fewer days a patient is in hospital the more money a hospital gets for a certain condition. If you have shaved all the waste out of your hospital and are operating on maximum efficiency, the only way to get more money is to kick a patient out before they are ready. In order to combat this less money is paid if a patient "bounces", or is re-admitted for the same condition within 30 days. Therefore nobody comes in with the same condition within 30 days. They always have something unrelated to their last admission.

Furthermore, the more complications a patient experiences the more money a hospital gets. I remember my first day in a Victorian hospital included an orientation to "DRGs" or Diagnosis-related groups and "coding". I never realised that if a patient has an episode of dysuria and an equivocal dipstick they can be coded as having a postoperative UTI and therefore the casemix payment jumps 50%. Similarly, everyone has hyperkalaemia or hypernatraemia at some stage, or pulmonary atelectasis, or a wound infection (even if no antibiotics are required), or acute urinary retention (averted at the last minute by the threat of an urinary catheter).

And as Stephen Duckett also pointed out:

Mr Rudd's promise to provide 60 per cent of hospital funding also risked generating a rise in unnecessary hospital procedures.

The fixed cost of running a public hospital accounted for about 50 per cent, with the other half generated by surgery and treatment costs for individuals. "That will be an incentive to increase activity," he said.

The Age - March 5, 2010

Lastly, there is another downside to Case-Mix funding. In order for it to work, the funding body must define what procedures and conditions it will fund. If a patient suffers from something unusual that falls between the "coding cracks" or undergoes a procedure that is not listed in the manual, then they are unfunded, and the hospital must pay for that treatment out of general revenue at a complete loss. This discourages hospitals from treating patients with unclear illnesses (House would never survive in a Case-Mix funded hospital if it weren't for the fact that he does so many unnecessary procedures), and also discourages them from performing or rolling out new procedures or techniques which may have clear clinical benefits but are not in the list of funded procedures, unless a way can be found to "fudge the figures".

Ultimately, the real reason for this reform is to roll out the cost-capping measures of the Case-Mix funding system nationally. It provides a means to control and limit recurrent expenditure on health care in public hospitals over the long term. All the other claimed "advantages" are merely spin. This is the only valuable, long term and lasting outcome of these reforms. No doubt they are necessary, but it is disingenuous to hide this from the Australian public by overpromoting the other aspects of this reform.

The Underlying Problem
I have long held the opinion that the cause of ballooning costs of health care in this country is not the ageing population, or the costs of new drugs or devices (though these things do obviously contribute). It is that as a society we are completely incapable of drawing a line and saying that "This is as healthy as you need to be. If you want more, then you pay for it." Both the UK NHS and New Zealand health systems have had to overtly ration health care. South Australia has basically banned varicose veins surgery from public hospitals. Currently we prioritise but we don't limit what we offer in public hostels.

I do not speak from the moral high ground. I am no more likely to deny a patient varicose veins surgery or repair of a small hernia as a renal physician deny someone dialysis or a panelbeater recommend doing nothing to an insured smash-up. Generally as doctors we can tell when a treatment is futile, or unnecessary but ultimately we are people, and just like our patients - if a treatment is funded, the risk is low, and it works, then why not use it?

There is a precedent here which flies against the argument of those that say the Federal Government does not have the experience to roll out these reforms, and that precedent is Medicare. Medicare is effectively a case-mix system delivered on an outpatient basis. If you see a doctor, and you have a certain type of treatment (which correlates roughly to a certain condition) then the doctor receives a benchmark payment (75% of the Scheduled Fee). If the doctor's operating costs (+ profit) are greater than the reimbursement fee, then they charge you for the difference (the "Gap" fee). If the condition or treatment is not in the schedule, then the Federal Government does not pay and you get lumped with the whole cost.

Similar to the proposed efficient cost system, the Schedule fee is regularly revised (or some would say regularly ignored) to reflect the costs of providing each treatment. Sometimes the fee goes up, sometimes the fee goes down. Usually it goes down relative to CPI, and has (over the last 25 years) been a very effective way for successive Federal Governments to cap outpatient and primary care funding costs. Notice how the NHHRC said very little about primary care funding reform? It is because this reform is already in place, and the only thing that needs to happen is to turn the screws a little tighter as was recently attempted to cataract surgery.

I would predict that the nature of the Federal Government hospital reform funding rollout (Gee that is a mouthful) will closely reflect the way that private hospital cover is funded. Let us assume that the Medicare Schedule Fee for a Laparoscopic Cholecystectomy is the "efficient cost" of providing that service. The Federal Government currently agrees to pay doctors 80% of the "efficient cost" of that service. The remaining 20% comes from the patient's private health insurer. Any additional fees charged by the surgeon is paid for by the patient.

Similarly, private hospitals receive a payment for that patient's stay in hospital based on the patient's condition and their procedure, which is partly funded by state and federal governments but also by private health insurers. If those payments don't meet the hospitals costs then the patient is charged a further gap fee. All that Kevin Rudd and Nicola Roxon need to do is take that same system, insert "State Government" instead of "Private Health Insurer", apply it to public hospitals and voila - you have Public Hospital Medicare, with the added benefit that you can limit or reduce the "efficient cost" reimbursement as much as and whenever you like. If you don't want to pay for a procedure such as lap banding then you just refuse to add it to the list of funded procedures, and then it becomes the Local Board and the State Government's responsibility whether they want to pay for these unfunded procedures that the public is clamouring for access to… and the Blame Game continues.

We talk about a safety net but we are not brave enough to discuss how high or low the safety net should be positioned, or who we are really trying to catch. It is political suicide to say that some people need to suffer or die for the benefit of the rest of the community, even if that suffering is minor, or the death is inevitable. This reform is not about the "Blame Game", or restoring control to local or regional communities, or even improving the quality of our hospital system or population health.

It is about controlling the costs of health care in the long term, and it will work… for a little while, at least. But as I have pointed out before to my colleagues, Medicare (and these new Efficient Costs reforms) are basically the Australian version of public Managed Care, and I hope that we do not end up at the end of a Get Smart episode with Max lamenting: "If only Managed Care and Kevin Rudd's health reform had been used for good, not evil."

Links:

Tuesday, August 18, 2009

10 Year Challenge

Seasoned readers may recall my previous post "10 Years in Limbo" about the 10 year moratorium placed on overseas-graduated doctors.

The 10 Year Moratorium applies to New Zealanders as well, as despite their special visa status they are not considered permanent residents even when enrolled in Australian Medical Schools, and the only way around this is to obtain permanent residency prior to commencing Medical School in Australia.

Well, Dr Mike Belich wants to do something about that, and he has challenged the validity of the 10 year lockout and is currently going through the courts, as reported in The Australian. To be honest, I don't really understand his argument for seeking an exemption from the current rules... but I guess this is how precedents are set.

No doubt all the New Zealander's over at Paging Dr will be all excited. I better go let them know...

GP goes to court fighting country duty - The Australian
(Click to Expand)

Tuesday, June 24, 2008

Heart Check? Blank Cheque! Part 2

ACA - Heart Check Con
ACA - Heart Check Con
Last year, I wrote a blog entry entitled Heart Check? Blank Cheque!.

It looks like our good friend, A Current Affair, has put their "investigative skills" to the case and done a slag piece on Heart Check. Please note that I had absolutely nothing to do with this - but I don't feel the least bit sorry for them.

Clearly this piece has had more effect than my blog entry, as this Heart Check Clinic Manager reports in her blog. Hopefully it has had no involvement in her marital difficulties.

Click on the image above to see the ACA video.

Monday, November 19, 2007

10 Years in Limbo

As a follow-on to a recent discussion thread over at PagingDr, I had cause to review the effect of the 10 Year Moratorium on Medicare Provider Benefits.

This has been a big deal because it effectively limits non-Australian Citizens or Permanent Residents from gaining access to Medicare Provider Benefits.

You may recall from the first instalment of my Mind the Gap Series that outside of the public hospital system the Federal Government funds medical services via the Medicare system (including the PBS and the Commonwealth Medical Benefits Schedule [CMBS]).

This renders the Federal Government extreme power and influence over who delivers medical care to the community via the allocation and restriction of Provider Numbers, and also how that care is delivered via limitations, restriction and conditions placed upon services before they are eligible for reimbursement via Medicare.

Note that this is a relatively roundabout method of control over medical practitioners. The Federal Government does not tell doctors what to do. They merely tell doctors that unless they do things in a specific way, satisfying Medicare guidelines and Ministerial Determinations, that their patients will not be able to have their medical costs reimbursed.

Therefore in theory it is not the doctor who is being punished, but the patient. Unfortunately, the doctor is the one that the patient sees face to face. The bills and invoices carry the doctors name. If the patient can't get money back from Medicare or their insurance company, it is the doctor they complain to, not the 17 year old counter chick at the Medicare office, or the faceless call-centre operator on the end of the phone line.

And if you are unfortunate enough to be one of the 90% of doctors that do not get payment upfront then you end up unpaid because the patient can't get their Medicare reimbursement.

What does this have to do with the 10 Year Moratorium?

Well, the 10 Year Moratorium is one of the limitations (along with Bonded Medical School Places) that the Federal Government applies to restrict access to Medicare benefits. It's purpose is to encourage doctors to enter and remain in the public hospital system, or to work in "areas of need" as defined by Medicare, brought in as part of John Howard's 1996 Provider Number reforms (More Info).

It applies to Overseas-Trained Doctors who migrate to Australia as well as non-citizens and non-permanent residents who commence studying medicine in Australia.

Basically if you fall into the target population, patients who see you in private (in your clinic or rooms) or on whom you operate in a private hospital will not have their medical costs reimbursed or subsidised by the Federal Government. In a system where patients are accustomed to paying little or nothing out-of-pocket this is tantamount to shutting these doctors out of the market, unless you do what the Government tells you to, and work where they tell you to work.

Fine, it's primary purpose is to encourage doctors into "areas of need". But what about non-resident doctors who gain their medical qualifications in Australia? These include full-fee paying students from overseas, as well as New Zealanders (who are on Special Category Visas) who study medicine in Australia. These students take up valuable medical school positions, but are discouraged from working in Australia for 10 years after their graduation, when they have careers they can easily go to in New Zealand and elsewhere.

Furthermore, they aren't banned from working in Australia - only from working outside the public hospital system. That means that they are free to pursue their specialist qualifications and postgraduate degrees (but GP trainees have to enter the Rural Training Program). After this, however, they have to go overseas or off to the bush (which increasingly means outer metropolitan urban fringes) to bide their time.

It seems a colossal waste of university and hospital resources to train people who can easily avoid the rest of their Provider Number limbo by heading overseas (and most likely never returning).

But then again, maybe the Department of Health knows what it's doing...

Exemption guidelines for doctors need fixing: report - The Australian
(Click to Expand)


GP shortage in outer suburbs: report - The Australian
(Click to Expand)



Tuesday, November 13, 2007

Medical Students are not GPs!

Will they never learn? Kevin Rudd announced a commitment to build Family Healthcare Clinics for Defence Force members and their families. That doesn't bother me one little bit. Go for it, Kev.

This statement, however, left me frustrated that both major parties continue to fail to appreciate how the medical workforce works, and illustrates the simplistic concepts that seem to underpin major decision making amongst politicians and high-level government.

He denied it would be difficult to attract staff to the new medical centres, saying Labor would also invest in more medical places at universities to boost medical workforce numbers.

Labor in health bid to retain personnel - The Australian, 13 Nov 2007

Every time the lack of doctors to staff new facilities is raised, the same response is trotted out: recruit more medical students. It sounds good. It doesn't make sense.

John Howard is not innocent of this. I have previously pointed out the problems with the Howard Government's approach to the training of doctors, but this was typical of statements at the time in February 2006:

Prime Minister John Howard's February 10 announcement of a new health package at the Council of Australian Governments (COAG) meeting has drawn both criticism and praise in its addressing of the ongoing shortage of qualified doctors.

At what Prime Minister Howard described as "an unbelievably successful COAG meeting", a package of health reforms were agreed upon by state, territory and federal leaders.

In addressing the shortage of trained doctors COAG announced that there would be 25 per cent more university places made available to train new doctors but that they would be full-fee paying university places. As a part of this, incentives are to be made to increase the number of qualified doctors which includes raising the loans cap for full-fee paying medical students from $50,000 to $80,000.

More Doctors but not via HECS - Epoch Times, Feb 14 2006


Putting aside the qualifications that are always involved in these pronouncements ("money is being provided - but it's up to universities to implement them", "money will be invested into innovative new training schemes", "private sector training will be explored") keep in mind that many of these places will be full-fee paying (i.e. only minimally subsidised by the Government) and that they could well be occupied by overseas candidates (i.e. ones that do not contribute to the Australian Workforce).

The lag time between recruiting a medical student and producing an independently practising doctor is significant: a minimum of 4-6 years before an intern is produced. Such an intern cannot staff a GP clinic. It takes another 4-6 years to do that, assuming that there are enough accredited training positions.

Depending on the specialty, such positions are limited by State Government funding of public hospitals (such as for surgery, medicine, and all of those hospital-based specialties), or by the Federal Government (via Vocationally Registered Provider Numbers for GP Trainees).

Furthermore, Provider Number and Medicare limitations means that unless a doctor completes a training program and achieves specialist recognition (including completion of GP training), they are effectively unable to service patients in the public sector. The 1996 Howard Federal Government hobbled its own ability to fill the need for GPs in its overexuberant attempt to reign in Medicare expenditure (Link 1, Link 2).

Of course, the traditional response is that training numbers are limited by Specialty College intakes, lining the pockets of specialists along the way. In reality, the Colleges go out of their way to accredit as many viable training positions as possible, but such positions can only be worthwhile if there is enough funding to treat patients and maintain throughput.

This is and will continue to be the bottleneck limiting the production of independent medical practitioners. Long-serving readers may recall that I have written about this before and while the terminology is being superceded by SET and PreSET, the basic principles remain the same.



There is a lot of talk about the impending "medical student tsunami". There is no doubt that we are turning out record numbers of medical students. Hospitals are also absorbing record numbers of Interns and RMOs, due to the enforcement of safe working hours, and the desire of these new generations of doctors to have a life outside work. These doctors are typically employed, however, in non-training positions.

Despite the best efforts of specialty colleges to approve more training positions, they are stymied by hospital and Medicare's Vocational Registration infrastructure. New graduates (and governments) are developing an expectation that they will come out of medical school and go straight into a training program, emerging as a specialist in the minimum amount of time possible.

Unless the incoming government realises that they will not be able to adequately staff these GP clinics without stealing GPs from other parts of the medical workforce, or they address all the rate-limiting steps in medical training, then we will continue to see short-sighted, short-term, sound-bite based health policy and workforce planning in Australia. We don't need politicians and political parties that make knee-jerk decisions and can't see beyond the next press conference. Unfortunately, that is all that we have to choose from.

Labor in health bid to retain personnel - The Australian
(Click to Expand)



More Doctors but not via HECS - Epoch Times
(Click to Expand)


Wednesday, March 21, 2007

Mind the Gap: Part 1 - Medicare



When I used to catch the tube in London there was routinely an announcement as the train approached - "Mind the gap please". I am thinking of putting one of these signs up at the private hospital around the corner.

It is not that I have any objection to gap fees - I have some understanding of why they exist. Unfortunately, very little of the general population does. So here comes a brief lesson on the private health insurance system as it stands in Australia. This is part 1 of a 6 part series providing a brief overview of the funding aspects of Health Care in Australia from the perspective of a health professional. I am not an expert in these matters, but hopefully enough to explain how the system works from a practical perspective.


1. Medicare

Medicare is a form of social service support introduced initially in 1975 whereby taxpayer funds cover the basic costs of patients to see doctors in hospitals, clinics, rooms or offices, and even home visits or tele-consulting. More information on the history and development of Medicare is available here and here. The amount of money that the GP or Specialist receives from Medicare is determined by
  1. How complex the problem is;
  2. What procedures or services the doctor performs or provides during that consultation;
  3. How long the doctor spends with the patient or on the consultation.
This payment from Medicare is called the CMBS Fee (Commonwealth Medicare Benefits Schedule) and is either paid to the doctor directly, or indirectly via a number of means.

The original intention was for patients to pay at least a $20 gap fee for any services provided by a doctor (primarily outpatient consultations including seeing, examining, diagnosing, ordering tests, and dispensing treatment to a patient). This evolved to a situation where doctors were given a recommended (CMBS) fee to charge the patient. The patient would then pay the doctor directly and then they would take their bill to a Medicare Office where they would be reimbursed for 75% of the CMBS Fee, effectively leaving the patient out of pocket 25% (the gap fee). Alternatively the patient could take a doctor's invoice to a Medicare Office where they could obtain a cheque written out to the doctor for 75% of the CMBS fee and then pay the remainder to the doctor directly. Cheque fraud by patients was common.

Because there was no cap on a doctor's total fee, the back-and-forth travelling incurred by the patient, and also the fraud problems caused by the above arrangement, the Government then tried to simplify arrangements by introducing Bulk-Billing, which involves doctors undertaking not to charge a gap fee in return to being directly paid 85% of the CMBS fee.

Similar fees apply if a doctor visits a patient at home, or while they are an inpatient in a hospital.

The biggest success of Medicare has been to introduce bulk-billing, and therefore hide the true cost of health care from the patient, effectively saying that health care is free, when the Federal Government is really just buying health care in bulk for its taxpayers, and demanding a discount from doctors while doing so.

In the meantime, the Government uses Medicare to control and dictate who, where, and how doctors practise medicine, by limiting provider numbers (numbers issued to health professionals in order to access Medicare Benefits), bonding doctors to rural placements in order to access benefits, requiring GPs to be "Vocationally Registered" in order to access higher benefits, and placing very specific limitations and conditions on individual procedures and items before claims for benefits can be made. For better or worse, in effect the Federal Government works as a very large US-style Health Maintenance Organisation (HMO).

More on this series next week.